Learning Objectives

Learning Objectives

By the end of this section, you will be able to do the following:
  • Identify periods of economic growth and recession using the AD/AS
  • Explain how unemployment and inflation impact the AD/AS model
  • Evaluate the importance of the AD/AS model

The AD/AS model can convey a number of interlocking relationships between the four macroeconomic goals of growth, unemployment, inflation, and a sustainable balance of trade. Moreover, the AD/AS framework is flexible enough to accommodate both the Keynes’ law approach that focuses on AD and the short run, while also including the Say’s law approach that focuses on AS and the long run. These advantages are considerable. Every model is a simplified version of the deeper reality and, in the context of the AD/AS model, the three macroeconomic goals arise in ways that are sometimes indirect or incomplete. In this module, we consider how the AD/AS model illustrates the three macroeconomic goals of economic growth, low unemployment, and low inflation.

Growth and Recession in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram

Growth and Recession in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram

In the AD/AS diagram, long-run economic growth due to productivity increases over time will be represented by a gradual shift to the right of AS. The vertical line representing potential GDP—or the “full employment level of GDP”—will gradually shift to the right over time as well. A pattern of economic growth over three years, with the AS curve shifting slightly out to the right each year, was shown earlier in Figure 10.7 (a). However, the factors that determine the speed of this long-term economic growth rate—like investment in physical and human capital, technology, and whether an economy can take advantage of catch-up growth—do not appear directly in the AD/AS diagram.

In the short run, GDP falls and rises in every economy, as the economy dips into recession or expands out of recession. Recessions are illustrated in the AD/AS diagram when the equilibrium level of real GDP is substantially below potential GDP, as occurred at the equilibrium point E0 in Figure 10.9. On the other hand, in years of resurgent economic growth, the equilibrium will typically be close to potential GDP, as shown at equilibrium point E1 in that earlier figure.

Unemployment in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram

Unemployment in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram

Two types of unemployment were described in the Unemployment chapter. Cyclical unemployment bounces up and down according to the short-run movements of GDP. Over the long run, in the United States, the unemployment rate typically hovers around 5 percent—give or take one percentage point or so—when the economy is healthy. In many of the national economies across Europe, the rate of unemployment in recent decades has only dropped to about 10 percent or a bit lower, even in good economic years. This baseline level of unemployment that occurs year-in and year-out is called the natural rate of unemployment and is determined by how well the structures of market and government institutions in the economy lead to a matching of workers and employers in the labor market. Potential GDP can imply different unemployment rates in different economies, depending on the natural rate of unemployment for that economy.

Link It Up

Visit this website for data on consumer confidence.

QR Code representing a URL

In the AD/AS diagram, cyclical unemployment is shown by how close the economy is to the potential or full employment level of GDP. Returning to Figure 10.9, relatively low cyclical unemployment for an economy occurs when the level of output is close to potential GDP, as in the equilibrium point E1. Conversely, high cyclical unemployment arises when the output is substantially to the left of potential GDP on the AD/AS diagram, as at the equilibrium point E0. The factors that determine the natural rate of unemployment are not shown separately in the A/AS model, although they are implicitly part of what determines potential GDP or full employment GDP in a given economy.

Inflationary Pressures in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram

Inflationary Pressures in the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Diagram

Inflation fluctuates in the short run. Higher inflation rates have typically occurred either during or just after economic booms; for example, the biggest spurts of inflation in the U.S. economy during the twentieth century followed the wartime booms of World War I and World War II. Conversely, rates of inflation generally decline during recessions. As an extreme example, inflation actually became negative—a situation called deflation—during the Great Depression. Even during the relatively short recession of 1991–1992, the rate of inflation declined from 5.4 percent in 1990 to 3 percent in 1992. During the relatively short recession of 2001, the rate of inflation declined from 3.4 percent in 2000 to 1.6 percent in 2002. During the deep recession of 2007–2009, the rate of inflation declined from 3.8 percent in 2008 to 0.4 percent in 2009. Some countries have experienced bouts of high inflation that lasted for years. In the U.S. economy since the mid-1980s, inflation does not seem to have had any long-term trend to be substantially higher or lower; instead, it has stayed in the range of 1–5 percent annually.

Link It Up

Visit this website for data on business confidence.

QR Codes representing a URL

The AD/AS framework implies two ways that inflationary pressures may arise. One possible trigger is if AD continues to shift to the right when the economy is already at or near potential GDP and full employment, thus pushing the macroeconomic equilibrium into the steep portion of the AS curve. In Figure 10.10 (a), there is a shift of AD to the right; the new equilibrium E1 is clearly at a higher price level than the original equilibrium E0. In this situation, the AD in the economy has soared so high that firms in the economy are not capable of producing additional goods, because labor and physical capital are fully employed, and so additional increases in AD can only result in a rise in the price level.

The two graphs show how a shift in aggregate demand or supply can cause inflationary pressure. The graph on the left shows two aggregate demand curves to represent a shift to the right. The graph on the right shows two aggregate supply curves to represent a shift to the left.
Figure 10.10 Sources of Inflationary Pressure in the AD/AS Model (a) A shift in AD, from AD0 to AD1, when it happens in the area of the SRAS curve that is near potential GDP, will lead to a higher price level and to pressure for a higher price level and inflation. The new equilibrium (E1) is at a higher price level (P1) than the original equilibrium. (b) A shift in AS, from SRAS0 to SRAS1, will lead to a lower real GDP and to pressure for a higher price level and inflation. The new equilibrium (E1) is at a higher price level (P1), while the original equilibrium (E0) is at the lower price level (P0).

An alternative source of inflationary pressures can occur due to a rise in input prices that affects many or most firms across the economy—perhaps an important input to production like oil or labor—and causes the AS curve to shift back to the left. In Figure 10.10 (b), the shift of the SRAS curve to the left also increases the price level from P0 at the original equilibrium (E0) to a higher price level of P1 at the new equilibrium (E1). In effect, the rise in input prices ends up, after the final output is produced and sold, being passed along in the form of a higher price level for outputs.

The AD/AS diagram shows only a one-time shift in the price level. It does not address the question of what would cause inflation either to vanish after a year, or to sustain itself for several years. There are two explanations for why inflation may persist over time. One way that continual inflationary price increases can occur is if the government continually attempts to stimulate aggregate demand in a way that keeps pushing the AD curve when it is already in the steep portion of the SRAS curve. A second possibility is that, if inflation has been occurring for several years, a certain level of inflation may come to be expected. For example, if consumers, workers, and businesses all expect prices and wages to rise by a certain amount, then these expected rises in the price level can become built into the annual increases of prices, wages, and interest rates of the economy. These two reasons are interrelated, because if a government fosters a macroeconomic environment with inflationary pressures, then people will grow to expect inflation. However, the AD/AS diagram does not show these patterns of ongoing or expected inflation in a direct way.

Importance of the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

Importance of the Aggregate Demand/Aggregate Supply Model

Macroeconomics takes an overall view of the economy, which means that it needs to juggle many different concepts. For example, start with the three macroeconomic goals of growth, low inflation, and low unemployment. AD has four elements: consumption, investment, government spending, and exports less imports. AS reveals how businesses throughout the economy will react to a higher price level for outputs. Finally, a wide array of economic events and policy decisions can affect AD and AS, including government tax and spending decisions; consumer and business confidence; changes in prices of key inputs like oil; and technology that brings higher levels of productivity.

The AD/AS model is one of the fundamental diagrams in this course—like the budget constraint diagram introduced in the Choice in a World of Scarcity chapter and the supply and demand diagram introduced in the Demand and Supply chapter—because it provides an overall framework for bringing these factors together in one diagram. Indeed, some version of the AD/AS model will appear in every chapter in the rest of this book.

Disclaimer

This section may include links to websites that contain links to articles on unrelated topics.  See the preface for more information.