Learning Objectives

Learning Objectives

By the end of this section, you will be able to do the following:
  • Explain the characteristics of a perfectly competitive market
  • Discuss how perfectly competitive firms react in the short run and in the long run

Firms are said to be in perfect competition when the following conditions occur: (1) many firms produce identical products; (2) many buyers are available to buy the product, and many sellers are available to sell the product; (3) sellers and buyers have all relevant information to make rational decisions about the product being bought and sold; and (4) firms can enter and leave the market without any restrictions—in other words, there is free entry and exit into and out of the market.

A perfectly competitive firm is known as a price taker, because the pressure of competing firms forces them to accept the prevailing equilibrium price in the market. If a firm in a perfectly competitive market raises the price of its product by so much as a penny, it will lose all of its sales to competitors. When a wheat grower, as discussed in the Bring it Home feature, wants to know what the going price of wheat is, he or she has to go to the computer or listen to the radio to check. The market price is determined solely by supply and demand in the entire market and not the individual farmer. Also, a perfectly competitive firm must be a very small player in the overall market, so that it can increase or decrease output without noticeably affecting the overall price and quantity supplied in the market.

A perfectly competitive market is a hypothetical extreme; however, producers in a number of industries do face many competitor firms selling highly similar goods, in which case they must often act as price takers. Agricultural markets are often used as an example. The same crops grown by different farmers are largely interchangeable. According to the USDA monthly reports, in 2015, U.S. corn farmers received an average price of $6 per bushel and wheat farmers received an average price of $6 per bushel. A corn farmer who attempted to sell at $7 per bushel, or a wheat grower who attempted to sell for $8 per bushel, would not have found any buyers. A perfectly competitive firm will not sell below the equilibrium price, either. Why should they when they can sell all they want at the higher price? Other examples of agricultural markets that operate in close to perfectly competitive markets are small roadside produce markets and small organic farmers.

Link It Up

Visit this website for current value of various commodities.

QR Code representing a URL

This chapter examines how profit-seeking firms decide how much to produce in perfectly competitive markets. Such firms will analyze their costs as discussed in the chapter on Cost and Industry Structure. In the short run, the perfectly competitive firm will seek the quantity of output where profits are highest, or if profits are not possible, where losses are lowest. In this example, the short run refers to a situation in which firms are producing with one fixed input and incur fixed costs of production. In the real world, firms can have many fixed inputs.

In the long run, perfectly competitive firms will react to profits by increasing production. They will respond to losses by reducing production or exiting the market. Ultimately, a long-run equilibrium will be attained when no new firms want to enter the market and existing firms do not want to leave the market, as economic profits have been driven down to zero.

Disclaimer

This section may include links to websites that contain links to articles on unrelated topics.  See the preface for more information.